Saturday 7 July 2012

Reith Lectures - Law

Niall Ferguson: The Landscape of the Law


Transcript

(Recorded at Gresham College, London and first broadcast on BBC Radio 4 and the BBC World Service on Tuesday, 3 July 2012.)
Sue Lawley: Hello and welcome to the third in this year’s series of BBC Reith Lectures. Today we’re in Gresham College in the City of London – its oldest place of higher education. This hall dates back five centuries, hence the creaky floorboards, which you may well hear from time to time.
The college was founded by a bequest of one of the shrewdest financiers of the Elizabethan age, Sir Thomas Gresham. Sir Thomas wanted his money to be used to pay distinguished professors to give free lectures to the people of London – a tradition which continues to this day. Well, our distinguished professor today is Niall Ferguson. His subject - The Rule of Law and its Enemies.
In his first lecture he set out his main argument that the West’s relative decline since the 1970s, has been in part the result of a deterioration in the quality of our institutions. In lecture two, he discussed how excessively complex financial regulation is the disease of which it purports to be the cure.
Today, he turns his attention to the law. Has the rule of law – the foundation of our liberties for centuries – now degenerated into the rule of lawyers? With his third lecture, The Landscape of the Law, ladies and gentlemen please welcome the BBC Reith Lecturer 2012 - Niall Ferguson.
(Audience Applause)
Niall Ferguson:
“The fundamental question the Chinese government must face is lawlessness. China does not lack laws, but the rule of law… this issue of lawlessness may be the greatest challenge facing the new leaders who will be installed this autumn. Indeed, China’s political stability may depend on its ability to develop the rule of law in a system where it barely exists.”
These are the words of Chen Guangcheng, the blind lawyer who was recently allowed to leave China to study in the United States after successfully escaping from his Communist Party persecutors. Less well known in the West, but more influential in China, is the legal scholar He Weifang.
In an essay entitled ‘China’s First Steps Towards Constitutionalism’, published in 2003, He rather more tactfully observed:
The Western legal landscape does make an interesting and illuminating contrast to China’s legal situation, revealing many discrepancies and inconsistencies between the two… [A]lthough China’s modern system was borrowed from the West … things often proceed in different ways between China and the West.
The theme of my third Reith Lecture is the landscape of law. I want to ask what, if anything, developing countries like China can learn from the West about the rule of law. And I want to cast some doubt on the widespread assumption that our Western legal systems are in such good health that all the Chinese need to do is replicate our best practice – whatever that may be.
What exactly do we mean by the rule of law? In his book of that name, the late Lord Chief Justice, Tom Bingham, specified seven criteria by which we should assess a legal system:
1. The law must be accessible and so far as possible intelligible, clear and predictable.
2. Questions of legal right and liability should ordinarily be resolved by application of the law and not by the exercise of discretion.
3. The laws of the land should apply equally to all, save to the extent that objective differences [such as mental incapacity] justify differentiation.
4. Ministers and public officers at all levels must exercise the powers conferred on them in good faith, fairly, for the purpose for which the powers were conferred, without exceeding the limits of such powers.
5. The law must afford adequate protection of fundamental human rights.
6. Means must be provided for resolving, without prohibitive cost or inordinate delay, bona fide civil disputes which the parties themselves are unable to resolve; and
7. Adjudicative procedures provided by the state should be fair.
My undergraduate study of history at Oxford taught me that the English rule of law was the product of a slow, incremental process of judicial decision-making in the courts, based in large measure on precedents.
I now realise that this was a rather naive view. As the greatest living theorist of law in the English-speaking world, Ronald Dworkin, explained in Law’s Empire, there really are principles of justice and fairness underpinning the common law, even when those principles are not codified as they are in the United States Constitution.
Behind the operation of the law lie two things: the integrity of judges and, to quote Dworkin: “legislation …flowing from the community’s present commitment to a background scheme of political morality.”
Now, to proceed from the ethical roots of law to its economic consequences may seem like rather a leap. But it’s not.
Few truths are today more universally acknowledged than that the rule of law – particularly in so far as it restrains the grabbing hand of the rapacious state – is good for economic growth, as well as just good.
According to Douglass North: “The inability of societies to develop effective, low-cost enforcement of contracts is the most important source of both historical stagnation and contemporary under-development.’
Enforcement of contracts by a third party is necessary to overcome the reluctance of private sector agents to participate in transactions over significant time or distance. The creditor fears the debtor will welch on the deal.
Contract enforcement can be provided by private sector agencies such as exchanges, credit companies and arbitrators.
But usually, in North’s words: ‘Third-party enforcement [means] … the development of the state as a coercive force able to monitor property rights and enforce contracts effectively.’
The problem is getting the state not to abuse its power – hence the need to constrain it. As Avner Greif has argued, if public contract-enforcing institutions reveal information about the location and amount of private wealth, the state, or its functionaries, may be tempted to steal it.
Where states are not constrained by law, therefore, private contract-enforcing institutions are safer, like the network operated by 11th Century Maghribi traders in the Mediterranean, which was based on their common Jewish religion and kinship ties. The defect of such institutions, as with medieval guilds, is their tendency to raise entry barriers and establish monopolies, discouraging competition and reducing economic efficiency. That is why private contract enforcement tends to yield to public, as economies become more sophisticated. But that process is dependent on constraining the state to use its power of coercion in such a way as to respect private property rights.
In economics, that is the essential function of the rule of law. It’s the property rights - more than the human rights - that are fundamental.
Neither the French civil law system, originating in the Roman legal tradition, nor the German and Scandinavian legal systems, were as good, to say nothing of non-Western systems of law.
What was it that made and makes common law economically better? In their seminal 1997 article, La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer and Vishny argued that common law systems offer greater protection for investors and creditors. The result is that people with money are more willing to invest in, or lend to, other people’s businesses. And higher levels of financial intermediation tend to correlate to higher rates of growth.
Like so many arguments in social science, this theory of legal origins implies a certain version of history. Why did French law end up being worse than English? Because the medieval French crown was more assertive of its prerogatives than the English. Because France was less peaceable internally and more vulnerable externally than England.
Because the French Revolution, which distrusted judges, sought to convert them into automata, implementing the law as defined and codified by the legislature – or emperor. The result was an even less independent judiciary and courts precluded from reviewing administrative acts. When the French exported their model to their colonies in Asia and Africa, the results were even worse.
The theory of legal origins also has important historical implications for non-Western legal systems. As He Weifang has argued, in the imperial era, Chinese government made: ‘no arrangement whatsoever for the separation of powers’ so that ‘the country magistrate exercised comprehensive responsibilities [including all] three basic functions, namely the enacting of rules … the execution of rules … and the resolving of disputes’.
Confucianism and Taoism deprecated lawyers and deplored the adversarial mode. Yet attempts to import elements of the British legal system to China were a failure. When the late Qing state belatedly entered the commercial sphere, it did so in a counter-productive way, over-taxing merchants and delegating power to monopolistic guilds without effectively constraining itself or its agents. The results were rampant corruption and economic contraction.
In recent years there has been something of a backlash against the legal origins hypothesis. Naomi Lamoreaux and others have pointed out that the French economy performed rather well, not least financially, despite not having the common law. Yet for me the theory’s weakest point becomes apparent if we just look at the state of the English common law as it was in the period when, by implication, it must have done the greatest good: the period of the industrial revolution, when the English and their Celtic neighbours radically altered the course of world economic history.
Here is a contemporary description of an English court at that time:
… [S]ome score of members of the … bar … are … mistily engaged in one of the ten thousand stages of an endless cause, tripping one another up on slippery precedents, groping knee-deep in technicalities, running their goat-hair and horsehair warded heads against walls of words and making a pretence of equity with serious faces, as players might…
[T]he various solicitors in the cause, some two or three of whom have inherited it from their fathers, who made a fortune by it… are… ranged in a line, in a long matted well … between the registrar’s red table and the silk gowns, with bills, cross-bills, answers, rejoinders, injunctions, affidavits, issues, references to masters, masters’ reports, mountains of costly nonsense, piled before them.
This is the Court of Chancery … which so exhausts finances, patience, courage, hope, so overthrows the brain and breaks the heart, that there is not an honourable man among its practitioners who would not give – who does not often give – the warning, “Suffer any wrong that can be done you rather than come here!”’

(Audience Laughter)
It might be objected that Charles Dickens was not being entirely fair to the legal profession of his day in Bleak House. Yet Dickens had started his career writing court reports.
He had seen his own father imprisoned for debt. His biographers confirm that he knew whereof he spoke. And historians of the 19th Century English legal system largely confirm his account.
First, we must note the tiny size of the system. As late as 1854, the entire judiciary of England and Wales sitting in courts of general jurisdiction numbered just fifteen.
Second, until 1855 there were severe statutory restrictions on the ability of entrepreneurs to create limited liability companies, a legacy of the time when the promoters of monopoly firms like the South Sea Company had successfully pulled up the ladder behind them to boost the value of their own shares.
Third, in the single most important sector of the Victorian industrial revolution, the railways, recent research has revealed that ‘English common law and common law lawyers had a profound and largely negative impact’. Solicitors were notorious as speculative railway share promoters, judges were publicly accused of favouritism and the Parliamentary Bar ran a nice little racket, effectively selling statutory approval for new rail lines.
What are we to make of this? Does history essentially refute the legal origins thesis that the common law trumps all other systems? Not quite.
For despite the evident shortcomings of the English legal system in the industrial age, there remains compelling evidence that it could and did adapt to the changes of the time, perhaps even in ways that facilitated the process as well as accommodating it. This point is best illustrated with reference to the 1854 Exchequer case - well known to law students on both sides of the Atlantic - of Hadley and Baxendale.
The dispute was between two Gloucester flour millers, Joseph and Jonah Hadley, and the London-based carriers Pickford & Co. The Hadleys had sued Pickfords for the full amount of their losses – including foregone profits – resulting from late delivery of a replacement hand-crafted mill shaft. It’s no coincidence that Pickfords are still around today and the Hadleys’ firm, City Flour Mills, is not.
For although the local jury decided for the Hadleys, the appellant judges in London reversed their decision. According to the American judge and legal scholar Richard Posner, Hadley and Baxendale enshrined the principle ‘that where a risk of loss is known to only one party to the contract, the other party is not liable for the loss if it occur’.
It was later said of the original Assize judge, Sir Roger Crompton, that he ‘never recognized the notion that the common law adapts itself by a perpetual process of growth to the perpetual roll of the tide of circumstances as society advances’.
That was certainly not the approach of the appeal judges, Barons Alderson, Parke and Martin, who – in the words of a modern commentator – ‘refashioned the substantive law of contract damages’.
As Alderson reasoned: ‘The only circumstances… communicated by the plaintiffs to the defendants at the time the contract was made were that they were millers whose mill shaft was broken. There was no notice of the ‘special circumstances’ that the mill was stopped and profits would be lost as a result of delay in the delivery of the shaft.”
So the loss of profits couldn’t be taken into consideration in estimating damages. To put it really crudely, this was a ruling that favoured big over small business – but that is not really the important point. The point is that Baron Alderson’s reasoning illustrates very well how the common law evolves - a process elegantly described by Lord Goff in the 1999 case of Kleinwort Benson and Lincoln City Council:
When a judge decides a case which comes before him, he does so on the basis of what he understands the law to be. This he discovers from the applicable statutes, if any, and from precedents drawn from reports of previous judicial decisions… In the course of deciding the case before him he may, on occasion, develop the common law in the perceived interests of justice, though as a general rule he does this ‘only interstitially’… This means not only that he must act within the confines of the doctrine of precedent, but that the change so made must be seen as a development, usually a very modest development, of existing principle and so can take its place as a congruent part of the common law as a whole.
I believe this gives an invaluable insight into the authentically evolutionary character of the common law system. In this lecture, however, I want to address a different question: How good in practice is the rule of law in the West – and in particular in the Anglosphere – today? There are four threats I would identify.
First, we must pose the familiar question about how far our civil liberties have been eroded by the national security state – a process that in fact dates back almost a hundred years to the outbreak of the First World War and the passage of the 1914 Defence of the Realm Act. Recent debates about the protracted detention of terrorist suspects are in no way new. Somehow it’s always a choice between habeas corpus and hundreds of corpses. (Audience Laughter)
A second threat is the very obvious one posed by the intrusion of European law – with its civil law character – into the English legal system, in particular the far-reaching effects of the incorporation into our law of the 1953 European Convention on Fundamental Rights and Freedoms. This may be considered Napoleon’s revenge: a creeping French-ification of the common law.
A third threat is the increasing complexity - and sloppiness - of statute law. A grave problem on both sides of the Atlantic as the mania for elaborate regulation spreads through the political class.
A fourth threat – especially apparent in the United States – is the increasing cost of the law: an estimated $1.7 trillion a year, according to the U.S. Small Business Administration Report, in additional costs arising from compliance with regulations. On top of that come the costs arising from the U.S. system of tort law, which the Pacific Research Institute puts at more than 2.2 per cent of U.S. GDP in 2003.
Well, one may argue about such figures. But my own personal experience tells a similar story: merely setting up a new business in New England involved significantly more lawyers and much more in legal fees than doing so in old England. Experts on economic competitiveness, like Michael Porter of Harvard Business School, define the term to include the ability of the government to pass effective laws; the protection of physical and intellectual property rights and lack of corruption; the efficiency of the legal framework, including modest costs and swift adjudication; the ease of setting up new businesses; and effective and predictable regulations.
Evidence that the United States is suffering some kind of institutional loss of competitiveness can be found not only in Porter’s recent work but also in the World Economic Forum’s annual Global Competitiveness Index and, in particular, the Executive Opinion Survey on which it’s partly based. The survey includes 15 measures of the rule of law, ranging from the protection of private property rights to the policing of corruption and the control of organised crime.
It’s an astonishing yet scarcely acknowledged fact that on no fewer than 15 out of 15, the United States now fares markedly worse than Hong Kong. In the Heritage Foundation’s Freedom Index, too, the U.S. ranks 21st in the world in terms of freedom from corruption, a considerable distance behind Hong Kong and Singapore.
Perhaps the most compelling evidence of all comes from the World Bank’s Indicators on World Governance, which suggest that, since 1996, the United States has suffered a decline in the quality of its governance in three different dimensions: government effectiveness, regulatory quality and the control of corruption.
Compared with Germany or Hong Kong, the U.S. is manifestly slipping behind. One consolation is that the United Kingdom doesn’t appear to have suffered a comparable decline in institutional quality.
If the rule of law, broadly defined, is deteriorating in the United States, where is it getting better? I recently delved into the Bank’s treasure trove, the World Development Indicators database, to see which countries in Africa are ranked highly in terms of:
1. The quality of public administration;
2. The business regulatory environment;
3. Property rights and rule-based governance;
4. Public sector management and institutions; and
5. Transparency, accountability and corruption in the public sector
The countries that appear in the top twenty developing economies in four or more of these categories are Burkino Faso, Ghana, Malawi and Rwanda.
Another approach I’ve taken is to look at the IFC’s Doing Business reports since 2006 to see which developing countries have seen the biggest reduction in the number of days it takes to complete six procedures: starting a business, getting a construction permit, registering a property, paying taxes, importing goods and enforcing contracts.
The African winners are, in order of achievement, Nigeria, the Gambia, Mauritius, Botswana and Burundi. Other emerging markets on the right track are Azerbaijan, Croatia, Iran, Malaysia and Peru. Yes, I did say Iran - but I would hold off on investing there this year. (Audience Laughter)
By contrast, The People’s Republic of China has achieved astonishing growth without good legal institutions and without much improvement in them. However, many scholars argue that if China does not now transition to the rule of law, there will be a low institutional ceiling, limiting its future growth.
The case of Bo Xilai’s anti-corruption campaign in Chongqing illustrates just how far China still is from the rule of law.
As He Weifang has pointed out, the Chongqing judges essentially acted as an arm of Bo’s regime, accepting extorted confessions and omitting cross-examination. For years, He Weifang has campaigned for judicial independence, the accountability of the National People’s Congress, especially with regard to taxation, the freedom of the press and the conversion of the Communist Party into a ‘properly registered legal entity’, subject to the law – including the currently meaningless rights in Article 35 of the PRC Constitution.
For those of us who live in the West, where lawyers often seem to have become their own vested interest, it’s strange to encounter lawyers who aim at this kind radical change. Today, however, Chinese lawyers – who numbered just 150,000 in 2007 – are a crucial force in China’s rapidly evolving public sphere.
Recent surveys suggest that they are ‘strongly inclined towards political reform… and are profoundly discontented with the political status quo’.
To read statements like the following, from a lawyer in Henan province, is to be reminded forcibly of a time when lawyers were in the vanguard of change in the English-speaking world, too:
‘The rule of law is premised on democracy; rights are premised on the rule of law; rights defence is premised on rights; and lawyers are premised on rights defence.’
The fall of Bo Xilai this year is one of a number of signs that elements within the Communist Party hear these arguments.
In a recent speech in Shenzhen, Zhang Yansheng, secretary general of the academic committee for National Development and Reform, argued that – and I quote – ‘we should shift towards reform based on rules and law’, adding ‘if such reform does not take off, China will run into big trouble, big problems.’
What we don’t know is whether or not China’s next experiment with importing the essentially Western notion of the rule of law will be more successful than past attempts. With good reason, He Weifang warns against naive imitation of the English, or American, legal systems.
In Shakespeare’s A Midsummer Night’s Dream, he writes in a rather engaging aside:
‘A person was changed into a donkey, and the other person cried, “Bless thee! Thou art translated’”
The introduction of a Western system to China is just like this. Common law translated into Chinese might well turn out to be like Bottom: a donkey, if not an ass.
Like the human hive of politics or the hunting grounds of the market economy, the legal landscape is an integral part of the institutional setting in which we live our lives. Like a true landscape it’s organic, the product of slow-moving historical processes – a kind of judicial geology.
But it is also a landscape in the sense of Capability Brown: it can be improved upon. And it can also be made hideous – even rendered a desert – by the rash imposition of utopian designs. We may imagine Oriental gardens in England and English gardens in the Orient. But there are limits to what transplantation can achieve.
Once-verdant landscapes can become desiccated through natural processes, too. Mancur Olson used to argue that, over time, all political systems are likely to succumb to sclerosis, mainly because of rent-seeking activities by organised interest groups. Perhaps that is what we see at work in the United States today. Americans could once boast proudly that their system set the benchmark for the world; the United States was the rule of law. But now what we see is the rule of lawyers, which is something different. It’s surely no coincidence that more than a third of Senators are lawyers, and a quarter of members of the House of Representatives. But how is the system to be reformed if, as I’ve argued in these lectures, there’s so much that is rotten within it: in the legislature, in the regulatory agencies, in the legal system itself?
The answer, as I shall argue in my final Reith lecture, is that reform – whether in the English speaking world or the Chinese speaking – must come from outside the realm of public institutions. It must come from the associations of civil society. It must come, in short, from us: the citizens.
Thank you very much. (Audience Applause)
SUE LAWLEY: Many thanks, many thanks indeed Niall Ferguson. So there you have it - a look across the landscape of law where the West is found wanting, and emerging nations such as China have fundamental lessons to learn. Let me turn to our invited audience here in Gresham College in the City of London. Ladies and gentleman, the floor is yours, though I can’t pretend that the professor will be putty in your hands - gentleman here.
JOHN COOPER: Thank you. My name is John Cooper, Queen’s Counsel. I’m also a Visiting Professor of Law at Cardiff University. But perhaps more pertinent to this question, I was also counsel who represented Occupy outside St. Paul’s in that recent litigation. You seem to argue in your eloquent lecture that it’s property rights, not human rights, that should be fundamental. In the Occupy case, it was the enforcement of property rights which trumped the rights of freedom of expression and freedom of assembly. Were the city’s rights more important than human rights?
NIALL FERGUSON: There are two points that I would make in response to that. The first was not to say that property rights were as a general principle more important than human rights, but from an economic point of view that they were more important. So that’s the distinction that I’d like to make at once.
The second point is that there’s a difference between the right of assembly and the right to protest and the right to squat illegally on private property. It wasn’t only the city that had a problem with the Occupy Movement. Harvard Yard found itself occupied for a period in the fall semester and this caused tremendous inconvenience to my students as well as to their professors.
I had no idea what they thought that they were achieving by pitching tents for a period of weeks in the increasingly chilly weather of New England since at no point was any articulate set of propositions made visible to me. So that is the distinction we must make. I would never stand in the way of people who wanted to walk through Harvard Yard one afternoon and express their dissatisfaction with the financial system - as I made clear in my second lecture, I have many dissatisfactions with the financial system too. But to pitch tents for a period of days, indeed weeks, and disrupt the life of ordinary people, that seems to me a very clear breach of the rule of law.
SUE LAWLEY: Question there.
LINDA YEUH: Linda Yeuh, Bloomberg’s Economics Editor, Economics Fellow at Oxford, and former practising lawyer. The Chinese paradox is as you’ve defined it, which is very strong growth and weak legal institutions. However, what has been under appreciated is the extent to which the Chinese have had institutions that don’t fit the formal definitions of what we think of in the West as rule of law or effective rule of law, and in fact it’s that aspect which has underpinned a great deal of its performance.
So, therefore, for you to argue that China has a great deal to learn from the West, the Chinese scholar might turn around and say do you fully appreciate the kinds of institutions which have arisen in China which are not common law derived. In fact they’re civil law derived because they derive from the major era of the Japanese, which was itself derived from the German system.
So in fact the Chinese picking and choosing of the law is very evidenced if you look at its statute. So, for instance, corporations have a supervisory board like the Germans do. So, perhaps my question is simply that - for you to argue there is a ceiling to Chinese development because of institutions. I would have to say you have to articulate perhaps a little bit more about what this Chinese paradox is and why they can’t continue down this road.
NIALL FERGUSON: There are two parts to this story and you mentioned one of them. One part is the legacy of the post-imperial, the nationalist era’s experiment with German-type institutions. There’s no doubt that they decided the English route wasn’t the one to go down and it would be better to copy some continental style institutions - rather as the Japanese had done. This did not work well. And it didn’t work well for a whole range of reasons, probably more to do with the fundamental instability of the politics of the nationalist era.
And that doesn’t mean - and I want to reiterate this - that there’s something fundamentally wrong with German or, for that matter, French legal systems. I hope you picked up my scepticism about the Schleifer argument about legal origins. I’m rather more agnostic than Andrea on this point and I think any real historian would be.
There’s a second set of institutions, though, that turn out to be more important as far as I can understand it in China today, and those are the informal contracts enforcing institutions in the private sector.
The thing that we associate with words like guanxi: the networks of kinship or of friendship which are often the reason that disputes don’t go to court or don’t get settled in court.
One of the interesting things that I read in my preparation for this lecture was the evidence that a huge number of processes that are initiated in the Chinese court system don’t actually ever get concluded or judgements never get enforced. And that tells us something.
It tells us that there is a private system of contracts enforcement going on. The question is can such a system which relies on a mix of imports and private contract enforcement be as successful as the idealised common law system of Bingham and Dworkin, and I think the answer is no.
The networks that run China are, we would say, corrupt - and economists might say inefficient. And this will ultimately prove to be a major handicap as the economy becomes more complex and particularly as the financial system becomes more sophisticated.
SUE LAWLEY: Come back on that.
LINDA YEUH: Just very quickly if I might. There is a very strong strand of argument the Chinese are substituting legal reform for effective political reform. And my own take on this in one sentence is that eventually the rule of law will hit the rule of the party and I think that’s going to be the point when China has to decide what its future ultimately is.
SUE LAWLEY: I see a former Reith Lecturer nodding hard on the front row. Tony Giddens there, Reith Lecturer 1999 I think I’m right in saying, aren’t I?
TONY GIDDENS: Also former Director of The London School of Economics. I wonder if one shouldn’t make more of a distinction between, as it were, first phase economic development and second phase economic development than you seem to do because the conditions which underlay the first origins of the Industrial Revolution anywhere in the world are arguably different from those once you’ve got a model to follow, and that might limit the application of common law and might suggest you’re using a rather British sort of centric view of the world because the state, for example, played a very important part in economic development and Japan, Germany, now in China on the basis that you’ve got something to copy, which you didn’t have originally in the UK.
And I just wonder also if, you know, you’re a bit too harsh on the state and government really. I mean we all know that, as you say, rapacious states need to be controlled, but the state is also the basis of legitimacy, it’s the basis of a monetary system, it’s the basis of many of the things that we assume as social and legal order, and if you’re going to control rapacious lawyers in the US, no matter how difficult it might be, surely it’s only government that can really do that?
NIALL FERGUSON: I don’t think that you can avoid the Anglo-centric nature of the Industrial Revolution. It just happened here first and that’s inescapable. Moreover, when one asks the question how did the state led models fare in the 20th Century, the answer is disastrously because in each of the cases that you mentioned - Germany, Japan, you might have added Russia - the power of the state to steer or accelerate industrialisation ended up being catastrophically abused, and as a result not only were property rights violated, all conceivable rights ended up being violated in Germany, in the Soviet Union and to some extent also Japan.
So, I think the lesson that I infer from it is that there was something preferable about the way in which things unfolded in the English and North American context. One ought not to be Anglo-centric in the sense of looking only at these parts of the British Isles we call England because the really important thing is the way in which the English common law was exported globally by the British Empire.
TONY GIDDENS: I do have to say I disagree fairly fundamentally with that and what I was saying was that the situation you sketched in was correct for the first origins of the Industrial Revolution anywhere, but after that you have a very different ball-game and I think continental law is much more interesting and much more positive than you seem to do.
I think if you look at Germany today, it’s clearly a leading economy in the world anywhere. Of course, it had to go through massive dislocations, but this was true of many parts of the world.
NIALL FERGUSON: Can I just say one mustn’t overlook the extent to which the original model, the 19th Century Victorian model that I sketched in both its Dickensian and let’s say its more positive light.
This model didn’t simply become obsolete because German manufacturing industry outstripped British. This model continued to be the framework within which the most successful economy in the world, the United States economy, flourished.
The US kicked these economies’ butts - to use American English - where it really mattered, which was in sustained productivity growth, rapid industrialisation, and constant technological innovation without the sacrifice of individual freedom.
DR DAMBISA MOYO: Yes, I’m Dr Dambisa Moyo. I’m an author and economist. I find your comment that China - I’m paraphrasing - should learn something about the rule of law from Britain or the West rather disturbing.
I should say that my fundamental belief is that the rule of law as a policy tool is actually largely irrelevant and in fact the rule of law is an artifact - or an outgrowth - of economic growth and, thus, the primary goal of policymaking, particularly in the international landscape, should be to ensure that these emerging economies can establish on a sustained basis economic growth and meaningfully put a dent in poverty.
NIALL FERGUSON: Dr Moyo, as a Zambian you of course must be aware of some of the less appealing aspects of the Chinese economic model since they are visibly to be… to be appreciated in your native country today. And that of course has become something of a hot-button issue in Zambian politics. The substantial presence of Chinese companies, mostly state-owned, in the Zambian economy was probably one of the decisive issues in the last Zambian election.
The African experience seems to me to be quite at variance with what you’ve just said, with all due respect. As African countries improve their institutions in the direction of improving property rights and political rights, so their economies do better. When African countries are run like China with a one party state, they do disastrously badly.
That’s surely the lesson of the post-colonial experience. And when you pick out. as I sought to do in the lecture, the countries that really measurably have improved their institutional framework, it correlates pretty closely with the best performers in Sub-Saharan Africa. Botswana’s the case that Paul Collier has written about and I think it’s worth reflecting on why Botswana is one of the most prosperous counties in Sub-Saharan Africa.
It’s not because they copied the Chinese model. It’s because actually, unlike most post-British colonies, they preserved a non-corrupt system of administration under the rule of law.
SUE LAWLEY: You mentioned then the African countries and other developing countries during the course of your lecture that had scored well in the polls - being good where you could set up business and so on.
I don’t know whether you were surprised or sceptical. I mean Nigeria, Azerbaijan are notoriously corrupt.
NIALL FERGUSON: What’s important about these measures that the World Bank produces is that you’re measuring improvement. What I didn’t tell you, of course, is that they were starting …
SUE LAWLEY: (over) Where the base is.
NIALL FERGUSON: (over) … in Nigeria (Audience Laughter) from an almost staggeringly low base. But the direction is important and those countries - Rwanda is, I think, a better example - those countries where there is improvement and you’re getting out of the foothills and up to something more like a mountain in terms of legal quality, I think there you actually do see consequences. But I specifically singled out the countries that empirically score well in those exercises.
SUE LAWLEY: (over) Okay.
NIALL FERGUSON: … because we need to ask the question: is this right? And I don’t want to make it seem as if I’ve got all the answers here to African economic development. I’m telling you what best practice in development economics currently is.
GEOFFREY ROBERTSON: Geoffrey Robertson. I’m a lawyer. I want to take you on this mantra that stopped the rule of law being the rule of lawyers. We do that, particularly in America, through the jury system but when it comes to judging governments, when it comes to deciding questions of power, we have no alternative but judges who are jumped-up lawyers, and it is the independence of the judiciary that is the most crucial aspect of the rule of law. It is the reason why London, not America or Paris, is the centre of arbitration, and so forth. It’s idle to talk about China ever undergoing a rule of law because it’s a country that cannot allow the independence of the judiciary. And you talk of Hong Kong - I’ve argued a case in Hong Kong for the Vietnamese refugees. They were succeeded in the Supreme Court. The Communist Party of China exercised its veto and reversed the decision.
NIALL FERGUSON: I think this is one of the key points that He Weifang and other Chinese legal reformers is that, as you say, the independence of the judiciary is the key; and the fact that in Chongquing essentially the judges were lackeys of Bo Xilai is probably the single most important thing that has emerged.
Initially when Bo Xilai was riding high, he could portray himself as the scourge of the corrupt officials and it was as an anti-corruption populous that he was really making his mark. But on closer inspection he was in fact running an extortion racket in which he would look at any successful Chongquing business operation and say ‘we’re going to do you for corruption’ and then they would take the chap away, interrogate him, the confession would be produced and the judges would say ‘you’re quite right’ end of story, no cross-examination. So I completely agree with what you’re saying.
You also made a really important point that needs to be emphasised and that is that enduring success of London as a centre for international litigation. Why is it that they want to come to London rather than, let us say, Shanghai? It’s a no-brainer: because the system here delivers a far higher quality of justice.
WILLIAM AYLIFFE: William Ayliffe. I’m the Gresham Professor of Physic. I’m really intrigued as to how you might reconcile the rule of law and the rule of property with the accumulation of capital by these economies, which completely ignored the property rights of the people they were involved with and, furthermore, even their human rights.
NIALL FERGUSON: Which economies are you talking about?
WILLIAM AYLIFFE: Well, I was thinking of the expansion of America into Native American territories. I was thinking of the British Empire in Africa - even into our lifetime - which ignored property laws and human rights.
NIALL FERGUSON: (over) Well I …
WILLIAM AYLIFFE: … as we’re finding out to this day.
NIALL FERGUSON: I highly encourage you to read my book Empire (Audience Laughter) in which I address precisely these issues. John Locke, of course, was the political philosopher who most articulately defined what property rights signified in his ideal commonwealth and it was Locke who argued that freedom, liberty, was essentially bound up with property rights. The self same Locke was of course the man who drew up a constitution for the slave state of Carolina, a constitution which explicitly defined the ways in which slaves would be treated.
At the heart of the expansion of England was a huge hypocrisy, which in some ways Locke personified - that the property rights were peculiar to white men. It was only gradually that that kind of idea was questioned. An obvious way in which that happened was the recognition that slavery was not legal in English common law. The famous Mansfield judgement in the late 18th Century fundamentally shattered the legitimacy of slavery as a legal institution, and within a very short space of time the anti-slavery campaign developed unstoppable force. So I think one has to recognise, in again taking an historical approach to these questions, the dynamic character of the discussion on human rights or, for that matter, property rights.
What people said and thought in the 1700s became very different by the early 1900s. The question really is - and this is the central point I’m trying to make - how does an evolutionary system differentiate itself from one in which absolute principles are enunciated and imposed from up on top? And the great benefit of an evolutionary system is it can evolve in the kind of direction that you implicitly favour.
SUE LAWLEY: Over here.
AILEEN McCOLGAN: Aileen McColgan. I’m Professor of Human Rights Law at King’s College London. You say essentially that the common law does it better than imported structures of rights, but isn’t the problem with the common law that its focus on property, in particular, serves to protect the interests of the wealthy?
And if you look at an area such as discrimination law, the common law was terrible. It did not deal with race discrimination. It was helpless in the face of sex discrimination…
NIALL FERGUSON: (Over)… But can that argument be upheld in the American case, where exactly these same issues had to be dealt with and exactly these same issues were resolved? I think one of the points that’s being missed here is that as attitudes changed on these questions - and they changed around the world at different times and in different ways - so law, legal systems had to adapt, and the implication that somehow the common law couldn’t, I’m not sure is compelling - at least if one looks at the US.
AILEEN McCOLGAN: (Over) Well, it couldn’t and in the US it was constitutional rights and then the Civil Rights Act which was legislation. It wasn’t common law.
NIALL FERGUSON: Yeah but I’m not saying you do… with all due respect, I’m not saying you don’t need legislation. The whole point about the common law is the interplay between what judges interpret as precedent and what the statutes new and old say.
SUE LAWLEY: And a last question here.
MICHAEL BRINDLE: Michael Brindle. I’m a lawyer. You talk about Ronald Dworkin’s views about law and morality, which I’ve always thought were beautifully expressed but rather confusing. I’d like your view on that, particularly in the context of the current debate about tax avoidance.
Our Prime Minister goes out and castigates one private individual for having acted immorally, perhaps in the hope that it might become illegal merely by being shouted very loudly. Has this got anything to do with law and has it got anything to do with the rule of law?
NIALL FERGUSON: I am the first to concede that much of Dworkin’s prose is opaque to me, but that’s a limitation of my intellect. I have never been terribly philosophically inclined. As I said, I’m an empirical thinker. I think there is a really important point that you’ve raised here, which is that if he’s right and that our common law system is in some sense derived from implicit principles, then it’s quite easy, isn’t it, to vary those principles if you make a loud enough noise. And this of course empowers an institution about which too little has perhaps been said in the course of these lectures - the press.
So there’s nothing more odious to me than the sight of the British media in one of their period fits of faux morality. I’ve mentioned hypocrisy once tonight in the context of British imperialism. Let me mention it again in the context of the British press - this kind of thing in which we stipulate that, while the law has in fact been obeyed, never-the-less some moral code has been violated, is perhaps Dworkin inspired. I could take it from him, but from The Daily Mail? That I think really crosses a threshold which I can’t bear.
SUE LAWLEY: (over) What about from the Prime Minister? Is it for the Prime Minister to stand in moral judgement on the taxpayer?
NIALL FERGUSON: One of my rules is never publicly to criticise the Prime Minister (Audience Laughter) It’s a very, very difficult job that he has to do and I’m sure, just as occasionally he leaves a child in a pub (Audience Laughter) now and again he says things which I’m sure on reflection he will realise were not entirely judicious.
SUE LAWLEY: And there we must stop. (Audience Laughter) Next week, for the last lecture in the series, we’ll be in Edinburgh where Niall Ferguson will be offering some solutions to the systems of politics, finance and the law, which he’s been holding up to the light.
And, as he’s indicated, he’s going to be arguing that the answers lie in our own hands. Until then, Niall Ferguson, BBC Reith Lecturer 2012, thank you very much. And from Gresham College in the City of London, goodbye.

Sceptism

Melvyn Bragg and his guests discuss Scepticism, the idea that it may be impossible to know anything with complete certainty. Scepticism was first outlined by ancient Greek philosophers: Socrates is reported to have said that the only thing he knew for certain was that he knew nothing. Later, Scepticism was taught at the Academy founded by Plato, and learnt by students who included the Roman statesman Cicero. The central ideas of Scepticism were taken up by later philosophers and came to the fore during the Renaissance, when thinkers including Rene Descartes and Michel de Montaigne took up its challenge. A central plank of the philosophical system of David Hume, Scepticism had a powerful influence on the religious and scientific debates of the Enlightenment.

With:

Peter Millican
Professor of Philosophy at Hertford College, Oxford

Melissa Lane
Professor of Politics at Princeton University

Jill Kraye
Professor of the History of Renaissance Philosophy and Librarian at the Warburg Institute, University of London.

Producer: Thomas Morris

Denis Didarot - a thing is not prioved just because no one has ever questioned it.Something that has never been examined disppsionaltlye is not properly examined. Sceptisim is the first step towards truth
Sceptism - nothing can be known not even this.

Since the Renaissance sceptism has been important in learning.

Every day use of scepticism - someone who denies orthodox view. Someone who simply disagrees with the majority
Philosophy - more about doubt than negative asertion - questioning, investingating.
Sceptism about the exteranl world - induction  - is there a respns that the future will resemeble the past
Sceptiscims about moratlity

Not about 1 or 2 specific things - simply an attidtue of doubt towards everything

An over of the discussion - scepticism been around for a long time - in ancient world took a global form - globla form of life. By doubnting or undogmatic one could reach transquility
IN modern world it cast doubt on a lot of cntroversial things. Casting serious doubt that people were concerned about
People like Descartes and Hulme in conteporary world were a living forve because they were hard to challenge
Is there cetain knowledge? If taken seriously the scepticism shows that we can;t prove what we thought ee did
ie sciecen has a solid basis is difficult to prove.
Morality and religion - scetical worries are strong where there is real big differences of opinion
No one has good reason for what is being asserted.

Alive is the subject of scepticism

origins - in Greek the words means investigateion
A kind of midesty of what is known and a relativism
Socrates - what I do not know I do not think I know
I kow that I know nothing
True knowledge comes fromt eh limits of knwoledge

Around the world - moral and religious beliefs could simply be local applications of ideas.

Customs ad practices were a source of scepticism - from the way cultures dress being different to bigger issues.

Generalisation 5th centurey bc - thought was strongly associate with religion - the dogmas of
First big moves away from this was Spcatrtes and plato
Casting dounts on assertions - such a multi gods.
Used in a way to reatonalise not disprove

A release of thought? Freedom of thought association - expcially in later sceptics - is Siscero

3 types - the acamdemic and the pyrinist schols
traced to 30 century bc

Wise man knows the limits to his nowledge.
To have knowledge have to have a criterion of certainy - the academics challenged this saying we cannot have certain knowledge

pirinist school - readical - they held that we could be happy and tranquil without wisdom at all
suspend belief of any dogma - ie snow appears white but is it really - so suspend that judgement brings tranqulitiy

Certain knowledge - stoic claim - there has to be a crriterion - not just appearance is it really tyhe way it is in reality
We cannot have sucha  criterion - any appearance that ay seem certain is indistinguishable and we dont have this criterion

Piro - pionist school
3rd century - nothing written - legends and rumours only
anythign writtten was later in 6th century ad
Nothing was in itself good bad honourable or dishonourable - nothing was more this or that
he took this to such an extreme he would not pay any attention to anything around him
it walking by a cliff he wouldn't turn away fromt eh edge. friends kept him out of harms way.
He lived to 90
Piro was criticised for not paying more attention to his emotions or anything
Completely even demeanour
Stories he would continue talking even when someone walked away because that;'s what he was doing#
Tranquility of a pig eating - the wise man simply eats and ignores everything else

He suspended judgement in thought - but there are contradictions as to whether he really did live this way

Nieztche -

He stood for   cetrl idea - nothing is more this nor that - compltte inmdifference - leads to suspension of judgement - leads to peace of mind

Repelles - painter - painting the foam on the horse of a mouth - couldn't do it - in the end he threw a spionge and got the effect he wanted.
Hellenistic era

Plato - Sisero - from Platos school
He studied in Athens - with academic sceptics.
He writes about the philosophers ideas that were not previously written
Romans - very practical people but not very interested in philosophy
He wanted to bring philosophy to rome
He write about the epicureans
the stoics

Sexctus Empiricus - sceptic
he was anti scepticism
Important - because - 3rd and poss most important influence on works that survived to tell us about scepticism
collected all sorts of teaching of Pironist school
Outlines of Pironism

differeent arguments

a systematic collector of the different ways of arguing - the reasons for doubt
He emphasised the prolem of the criteriosn - wnat a criterion of truth but how do you know what's true.
circular problem
Accepted the philosophy of scepticism

The idea was to suspend judgement - codified a way of arguing from wither side - brings you a poistion of suspension so not arguing for against
Should not even assert that we cannot have knowedge

Augustine -?
engaes well with Sisero - a phase in his pilosophical and religious beliefs
didved the world into good and evil two forces battling it out
Maybe they are wiser to say doubt everythign and there was no certain knowledge - as per sisero
But in christian pahse argues against sisero
There are some necessary truths - I err so therefore I am - i must exist to make mistakes
preempting Descartes
I know that it feels cold - something I know
He also thinks there is a moral and religious danger to be sceptic
What about scepticism allowing immporality - others believed it would lead to paralysis but he thought it could be danger to immorality
ie it's ok to kill/murder

rediscovered in Renaissance - ;atin printing
Impact - sisero acedemico
more people reading it and copied being made
people writing commetnaries etc.
Sceptic is the translated word from Greek into latin -
Lage works -
Impericus - script circulating in 15th century
Greek a very unusual skill language to read -

Latin in 1560's - translated by a protestant - published
with the life of Piro and Laertius and Gaelen - the best method of teaching
attacking sceptcism

Sextist - wrote against everyone
he wante to show that for every argeument there is an equal force counter arguement
for every dogmatic arguement there is a valid counter - therefore suspend judgenmt as not finite answer

The context - invention of pringint - vast cicrulation  translated into latin
and also a period of doubt - population gowring - new world being discovered
suddenly aware that preioous teachings not syaing anythign about these other weorlds
so question confidence in the beliefs that have been advocated asserted
a starting point for doubt and questioning

Galileo - discoveries - aristotle views being over thrown

Descartes = seceptism as useful tool to get rid of orthodocy

Montagne (Michel)
accesed transaltion - impact on him
Essays written carved mottos from Impericus - suspend judgement I examine I don't lean this way more than that way
Logo - a pair of evely balanced scales - propositon and counter propisiotn

Important to him - brutal wars of religion in his time
People killin each other over things they beleived - result of dogmatism - does not allow us not to know what we do not know
It forces us to take sides.Scepticims can diffuse this

Schools - we don't know wnayhting - compatred with the search for certainty

Descartes - a tool for the search for certainty - scepticism a moment ot overcoe
monologue - single mind enquiring rather than opposing the outdi views
searching for the foundations of knowledge
Atrrovius - we are trying to build solid foundations
Quesyion all beliefs so can reconstruct foundational beliefs

I think therefore I am
Je pense donc je suis - changed to I think therefore I am

Contraversial - agenda for scince for decades to come
Attacked by religions - undermining the foundations of faith - he thoguht he was backing up the foundations but people wouldn't accept that idea

Empty sceptical influence - lots of followers
New physics

The theme got carried forward by Pierre Bayol - influenced by wars in Farnce 0 a french priotestatn - hugenot
Toleration - scetpcism - dialogue rather than sinlge minded - lots of views from all over the place - contrasts - all of them intending to promote tolerance and realisationt ehre is lots to be aid on all different sides.

Intertwined throught eh middle centuries and then on

Antiquity - sure up christianuty - leave s roo for faiht
also a danger as underines uncertatingty adn all beleifs

Nephew - gianferancesco - reader of books in greek
Attacks all vain doctrines but defeniding christianuty

a follower of sernorola
The vanity of pagan learning

Get reid of pagan learning then people will turn to the church - power
Montagine takes the view that Piro shoed the man without power and reason which encourages him to take his inspiration from on high
like a blank tablet on which the finger of God can carve whatever he wants

Hulme )(David)
influenced by Baiol
Issue that arguemtnes are presented - scepticism then makes room for faith
Fideous - beliees on faith but undermines human reasoning
Hulme - an atheist - 1711
greatest works - Treaties of human nature
mitigated works later on - academic scepticism - different understanding as to that of the ancients
make us aware of how little justifaction there is for dogmatisims
idea of enquiry

Modenr scientist as a view

prob of external world - grapples with this idea
belief in external world is incoherent - doesn't make sense to think an object lasts through time
Careless and inattention - won't pay any attention to the arguemtns
and the scetpcism disappears

Ultimate view - different - much calmer and relaced
extreme views - disappear
The whimsical condition of mankind - we can expect stones to fall or billiard balls to bash into the other when we hit them
We can not justify our own faculties
Cannot take everything down to basic pirnciples

Scietific enlightenment - really can't do sciscne with progress unless absolute certaintiy - infallible info
Another school fo thought - Frech - we cannot get that certainty ony God has that certainty but can get a second level of certainty - sfficient to get on with progress
Hob Thomas - political philosophy - not form somethign we know but from implication
buiold up political scinece but not on a claim of knowledge

We kow less that the domatists but more than the sceptics

We can have a certain knowledge on somet hings - getting thourhg by applying the idea of reasonable doubt
Doubt is not necessarily fromt he oppistite of beliefe but can be simply inquisitiveness and checking outthe basis of things
We don't always have to look for more than probabaility
More or less the principle of scince - best explanation of appearances

Scetpical chemist - we can go forward on linited certitude.

Sceptisims to day - epistomology 101 - how can we refute the sceptic - basic philosopy - how can we know what we know

actually odenr science is infused with scepticism.

Bliss
XX



Rudolf Stingel



We had missed this exhibition but this painting was still at Sadie Coles. Fascinating how he had created this silk textured image by painting trhough gauze. Wow to have a studio and try these things out an experiments. I need a little canvas, some gauze and some oils with enamels and try this. It seemd as if he had painted through lace or something which isn't at all clear in this reproduced image.
I love creativity

Bliss
XX

Spiritual bling

It's not how much one gets paid, Bliss, but how much they give, that makes them rich.
Bling, bling -
    The Universe

This is so timely. When I've been agonising about how little money I have despite working really hard, even doing extra hours. And then I can't afford more than the basics. Paying bills and food and petrol - which is a lot since my journey is so long to get to work!! Grr and ugh!
This has really been highlighted when trying to organise a holiday with M. We had grandiose ideas we ralise as we are gradually coming to terms witht he fact that EVERYTHING is too expensive. It's so wet and miserable weather wise that campipng seems unattractive but the reality is we cannot afford much more. It's so upsetting. And also letting go of the memories of world wie travel in luxury styles. I feel so grateful to have had the travel experiences I've had. Gosh! Places so wonderful and exotic. There is a spoiling in it too though. Having been to these places I want more. How much that sounds like the addict. Having ahd some experiences is not enough, I want more!!

Bliss
XX

Darleks, diodes and delightful days

I'm fretting now codependently about T and her baggage. I'm trying to remind myself that we invited her along but that doesn't mean I'm responsible for resolving her issue. I am a bit list suddenly in this and it adds to my overwhelmed feeling right now. It comes and goes. If she came from the start I guess the costs are shared from the start ie petrol, accom etc. however I'd also like some you and me days. Gosh that sounds funny in writing. Plus and this may sound dreadful I have no idea how it would be being with T for 7 days. Probably easy and there will be space for private time I'm sure. I think I am pretty easy going as to arrangements - or am I demanding? Sometimes I think I over organise because I need certainty and struggle just going with the flow. I think I'm having a moment of crisis about who I am and what I want in this moment.  Probably would not send this text for worry that it would add to your worries especially knowing you are concerned about your mood. So part of me thinks I have absolutely no issues with T coming along from the very start and it makes practical sense. The other part of me thinks a simple couple of days meandering our journey with just you is what I'd enjoy. I've let her know again that we are doing some things the first 2 days and the plan is to meet her after that. I've also said about the limited space in the car. I'll be speaking with T tomorrow evening just so that you know.
I wrote this mind wonder yesterday morning. You see I am so codependent I do not what I really want and maybe it's because I really and truly don't mind. There are questions with both options. The first, spending time with M alone is real. It would be nice and we always have fun together whatever we are doing and however we have that fun. And it's true that being with T for an entire week is an unknown and there is an invasion on territory. However. I really really enjoy T's company and the other option is meeting T from the start. It would be more convenient for her and the costs would be shared from the start too. I really don't mind someone else coming along. I do have concerns about the competitiveness that can occur in me when there is a group of three. I can swing from being left out to trying to take over one friendship meaning that another gets excluded. God with your help thank You for removing this element of "game-paying" that arises within me even if it comes into play for anyone else. Thank You for the awareness and the foresight, therefore I welcome your help to remove this defect of character. What is the defect? Jealousy, low self-esteem, possessiveness. They are all off springs from one and other I realise. There probably is not one single defect there but several - although they all come down to self hatred and fear. God help me to not be afraid and help me to stop being full of self hatred in fact any hatred at all. It is destructive and unhelpful. Thank You God.

So I put the suggestion to M to see what she would prefer and God please help me to know which is the best option for all concerned.

I have a delightful day. I am looking after the pack - Molly, Harry and of course LouLou. The B's are going for a day out and it is an opportunity for me to have the entire pack all to myself. I a going to watch a film and read books and lounge about. I may even have a nap. Somehow, even though it is annual leave, it feels like a free day.
Oh and yesterday it was whispered to me by a friend that the HD is leaving in 2 weeks - rapid! And F is coming back as the HD. Yippppppeeeeee. I think my expectations are high for immediate changes and for the better to suit me. But the reality is probably going to be very different. Please God help to remove my expectations so that I am not even further saddened. I don't like the way I need to embark upon niggling away at the way L is with S. Whenever L is out of the way we gripe about her. There is something I get from it. And that is I exterminate her soul and that makes me feel better. So ugly, I don't want to do that because actually I know she has a good kind heart and shows it. She is very generous, in fact overly generous. What it does help me with is vindication. When I am uncertain as to whether her behaviour is bullying or in someway inappropriate I need some other way to discover this. It's almost childlike. Something feels wrong inside of me and yet I don't know whether it is or not because it seems to be coming from an authority. It is a parent-child situation for sure. So what I need to do is find an appropriate way to raise the question without sounding accusational. God thank You for this awareness. And thank You for showing me the way ahead. I need some help now to do this. It will be better for me as a person, checking rather than damning or assuming or being so flipping righteous. So what are the way to ask questions about this?
For example with her telling me/us several times that she is going to take on a clients request for L to sponsor, as in 12 step sponsor. It seems to me to be truly crossing and ethical boundary. I don't need FDAP or BACP to tell me this, it just seems far too blurred. I am sure I read in FDAP ethics that one should not befriend in any way a client before they are two years beyond the treatment sessions. And I'm sure this came up with the whole I and C situation. But L keeps quoting FDAP as if there is approval of such a situation and approval to take clients to meetings etc. It all seems so wrong and potentially dangerous even though I can't see all the possible dangers like S does. It's when I talk to her that more awareness of dangers arise.
I do have this situation right now where my friends sister is dating an ex-client. It was inevitably risky taking in a friends sister int he first place. But this was not what I expected at all. It feels awkward. I took it to supervision and got some good feedback. oddly enough I did not agree with PD's feedback. It was I and P who both thought there was something sinister under this guy. I think there remains something difficult for him to reveal and in fact I think it's his sexuality. I think R will get hurt along the way of this. But in the meantime my opinions aside I need to speak with D to set some boundaries. I do not want to talk about the P or individuals there and I also want to say that it feels awkward having worked with him and his wife but also to reassure him that the confidentiality act still stands. I will ask him next time if we could speak in private. I also need to speak with A, G and R to reiterate the confidentiality act. I will not speak even in jest with R about her time at the P. If she ever wants to talk to me about it then we can do that in private. I need to remain professional and keep my family world protected for me and for them and for us. It's important to me.

So today. I am going to watch Avatar the film. I'm taking my big art book that A gave to me for my birthday. I will take the work books and the Uni books. My courses are now confirmed for September this year and for January next year. I trust God that somehow we can work it together so that I have enough money to afford trips to London, galleries, holidays and of course firstly and foremost cover all my living costs - as well as have enough time to study to the best of my potential - thank You God. I just know it will all be OK. I would really like to study but I truly need your help in balancing all of this. Please show me the way you have in mind.

And that brings me to the JFT reading - the meditation part ....
"Many things can upset you and you can easily get off the track. But remember that God is near you all the time, ready to help you if you call on Him. You can not forever stand against God's will for you, nor can you forever upset God's plan for your life, even though God's plan may be postponed by your willfulness and deliberate choice of evil. A whole world of men and women cannot permanently change God's laws nor His purpose for the Universe. The sea of life may look very rough to us, but we can believe that our Captain steers the boat on a straight course"

Gosh! This was a powerful message suddenly. All of my conscious life (and I say that meaning the ability to listen and have thought process on such matters) I have thought of this in a very literal sense. In that a "person" outside of me is determining my life, in the minutiae. As if there is no choice and freewill at all really. It has always felt very controlled and controlling and imposition and a heavy load that I've rebelled and fought against forever. There is a devil in me that is very self-willed and mighty strong. I have no idea where this force comes from, whether it is an extra strong part of my individual make up and how much of it is powered by circumstances and influences from my childhood etc. The fact is it's there and now recognising it how am I going to manage it and channel it effectively, positively?

Bliss
XX

John Currin



At the South Audley Street Sadie Coles gallery I experienced up close and personal the supposed pornographic paintings of John Currin's latest work.
I thought they were beautiful. Flash painted in a Renaissance style, looking like fine bone china. His study of the women was quite beautiful even though a little risque in maybe one or two. I thought it was less pornographic and something much more loving. Only one made me feel something uncomfortable. I felt as if I was watching something sordid happening. I can't find any images of it online.
Basically there was a scantily dressed young woman whose face seemed frozen, smiling but either he could not bring her to life or her look is of terror. I tend to think the latter. A woman sits with her back to us but seemingly holding the woman who is central and looking out at us, directly. There are two men, dressed and to me they look as if the are leering over her and something sexual is going to take place. The scene is full. A sumptuous, flock-type wall paper, a velvet stool with gold braid fringe. The whole thing is so very tactile including the skin of the naked woman with her back to us. I wanted to touch the painting. Yet I also felt as if I shouldn't be there and didn't want the next thing that I imagined to happen. of course that next thing is stuck there in time and in my imagination. Scary.

Oh here it is (well nearly all of it)


Here's Sadie Coles' information sheet ....

In his latest show at Sadie Coles HQ, John Currin presents a new series of paintings centred on the female nude. These latest works combine the explicitness of his pornographic paintings of the last five years with a new level of psychological realism. In contrast to those works, which drew upon 1970s magazines, the majority were painted directly from life in the artist's studio. They show reclining women who appear ambiguously caught between the art-historical trope of female nude and appearance of earthy naturalism.
Paradigms of womanhood (milky skin, alluring smiles) run up against incongruous details such as underarm hair and overabundant flesh. Otiose strings of pearls and expanses of lustrous fabric offset the ephemeral bodies of the fashion of memento mori. AT the same time, there is a knowing parallel between the awkward artifice of the women's postures and nakedness, and the phony luxury of their accoutrement's and surroundings.
Reflecting these shifts between the generic and individualised, Currin has punctuated the anonymous series with a small portrait of his wife (which was gorgeous - there were two of them. She is so attractive, in fact delicately beautiful and is an artist herself, Rachel Feinstein - my words not Sadie Coles). But as with other models, her expression conveys an air of ethereal inscrutability. The women's smiles are frequently as enigmatic as the timeless "archaic smiles" of  Greek statuary, while elsewhere their expressions are slipping into barely-concealed grimaces - as if directed back at the notional prurience and voyeurism of the viewer.
An element of caricature recurs in many works, linking them with the faintly grotesque personae of Currin's earlier output. In a large scale picture - a tableau, in contrast to the single portraits which dominate the exhibition - a nude woman sits flanked by suited, leering men and a half naked female companion. Through this compressed narrative, which suggests a modern-day reworking of the chauvinistic scene in Manet's Dejeuner sur l'herbe (1863), the artist throws light on the sordid underbelly of contemporary American society.


Currin has spoken of pornography in art as a "cliche of transgression". The traumatisation of the 'rude' pornography into the 'polite' idiom of old-masterly painting is furthermore a foil for an underlying element of subversion in his work - their strange dualism of 'bad' drawing and virtuoso painting. His figures' elongated limbs and awkward postures introduce a note of expressionism - echoing the more overt distortions of Otto Dix or George Grosz. (hmm? I'm struggling to see the connection with Dix and Grosz - Less than tenuous for me). In one painting, a figure is curled almost into the posture of a praying mantis on top of a bed of green plush.
Currin's new body of work responds to the grand sweep of art history in a dual spirit of caricature and veneration, playing upon the conceits and absurdities of painting at the same time as affirming its vitality. Through his often explicit content, he unravels the elements of sexuality or tawdriness which lurk implicitly with many masterpieces of the Renaissance and after. A host of unresolved tensions - virtuosic painting and awry drawing; elegance and vulgarity; sincere and irony - are at work in Currin's latest work. Beneath their surface bravura, the canvasses re-examine some of the enduring and vital contradictions of western painting.

John Currin (born 1962) is an American painter. He is best known for satirical figurative paintings which deal with provocative sexual and social themes in a technically skillful manner. His work shows a wide range of influences, including sources as diverse as the Renaissance, popular culture magazines, and contemporary fashion models. He often distorts or exaggerates the erotic forms of the female body. (Wikipedia)

To be honest I'm not sure about the leaflet information. It seems very speculative and making tenuous links. I think it's a little pretentious. However, it is one persons view and the job of the curator to bring the art to life I think. I am sure the woman we spoke to said that they were all sold and had been sold from £1.5m upwards. Blimey!!
I cannot recall a praying mantis pose but then I am already losing the minds eye images experienced today. I was particularly taken with the woman with pearls. It was truly delightful. The nudity did not seem pornographic but perhaps I've become so accustomed to paintings of the woman;s form. But that was what it seemed to be. A fascinated study of woman's form. There was one that was suggestive. There is was at the foot of the woman, with legs apart and the hint of her lace stocking tops, and her hand resting lightly on her most womanly mount. It reminded me strongly of Egon Schiele. And indeed when I searched for images there was a link up with the very Schiele work I was thinking of. In fact there was one portrait, not nude, that reminded me in looks of the Schiele model.
probably one of my favourites






Learning something new ....Memento mori is a Latin phrase translated as "Remember your mortality", "Remember you must die" or "Remember you will die". It refers to a genre of artworks that vary widely but which all share the same purpose: to remind people of their mortality, an artistic theme dating back to antiquity. (Wikipedia).

Wilhelm Heinrich Otto Dix (2 December 1891 – 25 July 1969) was a German painter and printmaker, noted for his ruthless and harshly realistic depictions of Weimar society and the brutality of war. Along with George Grosz, he is widely considered one of the most important artists of the Neue Sachlichkeit.



The New Objectivity (Neue Sachlichkeit) is a term used to characterize the attitude of public life in Weimar Germany as well as the art, literature, music, and architecture created to adapt to it. Rather than some goal of philosophical objectivity, it was meant to imply a turn towards practical engagement with the world—an all-business attitude, understood by Germans as intrinsically American: "The Neue Sachlichkeit is Americanism, cult of the objective, the hard fact, the predilection for functional work, professional conscientiousness, and usefulness."
The term was originally the title of an art exhibition staged by Gustav Friedrich Hartlaub, the director of the Kunsthalle in Mannheim, to showcase artists who were working in a post-expressionist spirit, but it took a life of its own, going beyond Hartlaub's intentions. As these artists rejected the self-involvement and romantic longings of the expressionists, Weimar intellectuals in general made a call to arms for public collaboration, engagement, and rejection of romantic idealism.
The movement essentially ended in 1933 with the fall of the Weimar Republic and the rise of the Nazis to power.

George Grosz (July 26, 1893 – July 6, 1959) was a German artist known especially for his savagely caricatural drawings of Berlin life in the 1920s. He was a prominent member of the Berlin Dada and New Objectivity group during the Weimar Republic before he emigrated to the United States in 1933.



Title - Suicide



I would love to own and run a gallery. I wonder who I could learn from? I will ask T. I would also love to be involved in a Bauhaus type centre of creativity. A place for the most creative to live and breathe and adventure with artists wanting to explore their particular art. How innovative and exciting.

Oh and then I went off to the New Burlington Place Sadie Coles gallery. As I travelled on foot I passed by an exhibition of Calder. Now this is the work of a man that ignited the art in my soul. Visiting Juan les Pins, which as I write it I have pangs to live there even now, we visited Le Musee Picasso.
http://www.antibes-juanlespins.co.uk/le-musee-picasso/antibes/tabid/3491/offreid/cc136a95-5719-488b-aa57-89cd06dfcfc9/art-and-culture-details.aspx

Wow what an amazing experience and I wasn't truly conscious of it at the time. I so wish I could revisit with what I know now. I have been so very fortunate indeed in my life. I wish I had been more cultured and appreciated more fully what I was privileged to experience. Anyway within the Musee was an exhibition of Calder. Suddenly my heart and soul were uplifted and beholden by his work. I was also lucky enough to see his work in Washington DC. And there I was walking past some more of his work - where my whole art story truly began. I wanted to take a photo, looking in to the private party. A guard was o the door. I wish I could have taken that photo or have been brave enough to ask to enter. Maybe if I had told my story they would have allowed me in for a moment. Thinking back on what I surveyed, it was all women and children. Hmm interesting.

Anyway I the went to Sadie Coles - Secret Life - Jonathan Horowitz and Elizabeth Peyton.
I will scan the document and add it to this page. Not tonight though as I feel slightly jaded now.
I saw a very intriguing book there called My Secret Life by anonymous. A very sexually explicit boo of learning by a writer never known but guessed at. I was looking for copies through Amazon and eBay but they are very expensive indeed. Interesting how pornography or erotica is very much heightened mode right now - or rather comes to find me. I am curious to read Fifty Shades of Gray. I read a book in my teens called The House of Joy. I think that was actually the Nazi prioner of war camp. No there was another book about the sexual romp of a young woman leaving home and becoming involved with the sex industry. I was intrigued then and went on to expriment myself always with that book in mind.

FA as always was very enlightening. I was chatty with C, a person who I have thought to be frosty towards me. She was so much friendlier and approachable. I had lunch chatting. And then C joined me on the journey to Bond Street and the walk to Sadie Coles. Oh I went to see the Sarah Lucas part of the gallery too and have some photos to add later. Interesting. I saw her too.

A very interesting day. How exciting that I am branching out from main galleries and exhibitions. However a date is in the diary for the Munch exhibition. I think we will need to buy tickets in advance..... 11th August is the date set.

Bliss
XX

My photos from the day .............